2008 Guy Mhone Memorial Conference on Development
The Council for the Development of Social Science Research in Africa (CODESRIA) invites abstracts and proposals for paper presentation at the second international conference it is organising on development as part of its revamped Economic Policy Research Programme. The first conference within the framework of this initiative was convened in 2007. The theme of the 2008 conference is Re-thinking Trade and Industrial Policy for African Development.
CODESRIA
Conference Announcement and Call for Proposals
2008 Guy Mhone Memorial Conference on Development
Theme: Rethinking Trade and Industrial Policy for African Development
Date: 25 – 27 July, 2008 -
Venue: Lusaka, Zambia.
The Council for the Development of Social Science Research in Africa (CODESRIA) invites abstracts and proposals for paper presentation at the second international conference it is organising on development as part of its revamped Economic Policy Research Programme. The first conference within the framework of this initiative was convened in 2007. The theme of the 2008 conference is: Re-thinking Trade and Industrial Policy for African Development. The conference is being convened in the context of the Council’s current commitment to promoting a critical re-thinking of all aspects of socio-economic development in Africa; it is also held to honour the memory of one of the continent’s most distinguished development thinkers and former member of the CODESRIA Executive Committee, the late Professor Guy Mhone. The conference will take place in Lusaka, Zambia, from 25 to 27 July, 2008. As a domain of research and policy action, trade and industrial policy is recognised as central to the development prospects of any country, and the countries of Africa are not an exception in this regard. What has been in contention over the years has been the most appropriate type of trade and industrial policy that would respond most effectively to the needs of countries at different stages of development. The intellectual roots of the contemporary debates on trade and industrial policy go back to the works of the earliest political economists; indeed, it constituted one of the central concerns addressed by Adam Smith and David Ricardo in their historic diatribe against the mercantilists. The metaphor of “free trade” that was deployed against the mercantilists and the interests who were its most vociferous bearers spoke to the quest for competitive advantage at a time when the modern industrial revolution was gathering steam. Not surprisingly, those that had an edge in the process of industrialisation pushed the hardest for “free trade” whilst those with an ambition to industrialise were more reticent, opting instead either for full protection or selective opening in order to nurture their nascent industries in readiness for global competition. Clearly, the trade and industrial policy framework adopted by the earliest industrial economies of the modern period like the United Kingdom, France and Germany, were crucial to their development in the first instance and the subsequent efforts they made to protect their historic advantages. Later industrialisers like Japan and the United States were to learn to calibrate their trade and industrial policy in ways which enabled them to grow their economies, overcome structural obstacles to their economic transformation, and then compete with other major players for global economic dominance. More recent and emerging industrial powerhouses like South Korea, Thailand, China and India are themselves relying heavily on trade and industrial policy as a key instrument for their economic development. Their experience suggests, as did the experiences of others before them, that the ideology of “free trade” is not to be taken on face value, and the actual practises of states need to be read much more seriously. During the late colonial period, that enigmatic phase in the history of colonial rule which, for the first time, saw the germination of some measure of development thinking in the discourses and policies of the colonial authorities, the very first steps towards the formulation of a modern trade and industrial policy for Africa were taken. These steps basically entailed the introduction of tariffs that, at one level, sought to regulate importation and exportation with a view deliberately to maximising internal revenues, reducing foreign exchange outlays, improving the trade balance, and strengthening domestic production beyond primary agricultural production. At another level, the trade and industrial policy pursued during the late colonial period was aimed at responding to emerging structural shifts in the local and global economies that also translated into social and political pressures for an acceleration of the development of the colonial economies. These pressures were aimed at moving the post-1945 colonial economies beyond the simple production and supply of raw materials, and ensuring that they occupied a higher position in the international value chain that would at least begin more effectively employ the expanding pool of skilled labour available in the colonies. It was out of the trade and industrial policy of the late colonial period that the earliest experiences of industrialisation, most of it in simple, light manufacturing activities, emerged in various parts of Africa. The basic trade and industrial policy framework developed in the late colonial period was carried over into the post-colonial period and fed into various national strategies that were aimed, among others, at accelerating the development of the local economy, attracting domestic and external investment, promoting the home market, encouraging local research and development, achieving accelerated technology transfer, reducing import dependence, achieving rapid industrialisation, and increasing local content. As in the late colonial period, the state assumed a key role in the definition and operationalisation of trade and industrial policy; indeed, within the context of the state-led model of development which African countries followed after independence, the state played a commanding role which also entailed various degrees of central planning. Within this framework, trade and industrial policy involved the state both as leading actor and a prime facilitator. As actor, the state took a direct role in investing in the economy, especially in large-scale agricultural projects and industry. As facilitator, it offered various incentives to private investors and partnered with them as necessary in order to achieve its defined objectives of accelerating local development. The tariff regime was central to the trade and industrial policy and it was underpinned by a philosophy and an incentives structure that sought to discourage the importation of a range of simple consumer goods, facilitated the importation of intermediate and capital goods, and protected local infant industries. The consumer goods whose importation was allowed were brought in either on the basis of temporary waivers to address specific national exigencies or were subject to heavy duties that aimed at ensuring that they did not squeeze locally-made alternatives from the domestic market. Subsidies were also employed to reinforce aspects of the tariff regime put in place as were tax holidays granted to investors in the manufacturing sector. As post-independence commitments to economic cooperation and integration among African states gathered momentum, the tariff policies that were pursued were also adapted to accommodate African cooperation and integration partners. Preferential trade agreements that similarly had a bearing on trade and industrial policy were also concluded by African countries with major international economic blocs such as the European Union.
If trade and industrial policy in the first two decades of independence allowed not only for a central role for the state but also contributed to the growth and expansion of import-substitution industries, the state-led model of accumulation within which it was nestled was to come under severe attack in the period from the 1980s onwards. The grounds on which the import-substitution industrialisation model was attacked and subsequently dismantled are many and are all too familiar to merit recounting here in any great detail. Suffice it to note that the model was criticised for rewarding inefficiency, undermining national competitiveness, breeding corruption, straining the foreign exchange earnings of African countries, penalising consumers, discouraging technology transfer, and obstructing the efficient allocation of investments. The economic crises which African countries experienced one after the other from the beginning of the 1980s called the state-led model of development into question and paved the way for the efforts championed by the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the World Bank and the World Trade Organisation (WTO) to revamp trade and industrial policy on the continent along lines which were deemed to be compatible with the “free market” principles for which they were and still remain the frontline partisans. Within the framework of the structural adjustment programme which they pursued in different African countries, the international financial institutions pushed for the liberalisation of trade and investments, the generalised opening up of national economies, the removal of tariff walls that cushioned local infant industry, the elimination of subsidies that favoured local manufacturers, the liberalisation of interests and exchange rates, the decontrol of prices, the reversal of the frontline role taken by the state, the dismantling of national planning systems, and the introduction of a variety of complementary measures designed to entrench a free market system, promote an open trade regime, and deepen the role of the private sector in national economic development. The WTO treaty framework was also to be deployed to lock-in most of the trade liberalisation policies promoted by the IMF and the World Bank, and to extend the remit of the “free trade” principle to new domains that were binding on members.
Much has been written on the consequences of the shifts that occurred in trade and industrial policy during the 1980s and 1990s from a state-led to a market-driven model of accumulation. The consequences observed are multiple but perhaps the most widely discussed has been the systematic de-industrialisation of African countries, returning many of them to a basic role in the international division of labour as producers and suppliers of unprocessed or minimally processed raw materials. At the same time, consumer goods of various kinds have flooded local economies while revenue from import duties underwent a generalised decline. Furthermore, in most countries, the promise that the market-based structural adjustment framework would, by and by, usher in new “sunshine” industries that would be less dependent on protection and subsidies but, rather forged through free market competition and, therefore, more resilient did not materialise. Yet, it is inconceivable that Africa could ever hope to turn the table of underdevelopment without an appropriate trade and industrial policy that would enable it industrialise itself with all the accompanying direct and indirect benefits. This was a message that was consistently reiterated in many of Guy Mhone’s own writings even as he urged African governments to adopt heterodox macro-economic policies in order to have any prospects of securing their development in a neo-liberal global age. It is to the kind of developmental trade and industrial policy which Africa needs to embrace that CODESRIA wishes through the 2008 Guy Mhone Memorial Conference on Development to focus the attention of African researchers. A thorough re-thinking of trade and industrial policy in Africa is made urgent by several factors, among them the prolonged economic crises of African countries that calls for the abandonment of the orthodoxy that has dominated socio-economic policy-making over the last two and half decades; the open admission by the World Bank, after 25 years of zealous experimentation, that the structural adjustment framework which it so frantically pursued had failed to meet set objectives the immense pressures that continue nevertheless to be mounted on African governments to toe the line of “free trade”; and the one-sided push by the European Union for Economic Partnership Agreements (EPAs) with African countries. Among the themes that the conference will cover are:
1. Trade and Industrial Policy: Conceptual and Theoretical Questions;
2. A Re-Reading of Trade and Industrial Policy in the Post-Colonial Period: 1960 – 1980;
3. Trade and Industrial Policy during the Structural Adjustment Years: 1980 – 2000;
4. Trade and Industrial Policy and the WTO Process;
5. Trade and Industrial Policy in the Context of Neo-Liberal Globalisation;
6. Trade and Industrial Policy and the Dynamics of Regional Cooperation and Integration;
7. Trade and Industrial Policy and Technology Transfer;
8. The European Union - African Economic Partnership Agreements and the Challenges of African Development;
9. Beyond Neo-Liberal Orthodoxy: Trade and Industrial Policy for National and Continental Development;
10. Towards a Developmental Trade and Industrial Policy for Africa: Theoretical and Empirical Issues; and
11. Comparative Trade and Industrial Policy: Experiences and Lessons from other Regions of the World. Researchers interested in participating in the conference are invited to send their abstracts and paper proposals to CODESRIA by 30 April, 2008. If selected, the abstracts/proposals would need to be developed into full conference papers that should be received by CODESRIA no later than 31 May, 2008. Full papers adjudged to be of suitable quality by the independent selection committee that will review all applications will be notified of the results of the process by 20 June, 2008 together with information on travel and lodging in Lusaka, Zambia. All abstracts and full papers should be addressed to:
CODESRIA
(Attention: The 2008 Guy Mhone Memorial Conference on Development),
BP 3304, CP 18524,
Dakar, Senegal.
Tel: +221 33 825 98 22/23 -
Fax: +221 33 824 12 89
E-mail: [email][email protected] -
Website: http://www.codesria.org